Category Archives: Luke

Discussion of Luke and Acts of the Apostles

Rembrandt and Jesus’ face

Rembrandt and Le Lorrain exhibits at the Louvre. The first painting at the entrance of the Rembrandt exhibit is most striking: The Emmaus disciples, a painting from 1628-9 (Rembrandt was 23), at the moment they recognize their traveling companion as the resurrected, stunningly backlit Jesus. What does recognition mean here? a remembrance of one’s own origins in the self-giving other, a transfiguration. Their eyes have suddenly opened at the breaking of bread, as he had opened the scriptures for them, that is, as he had broken the book open for them. Same verb “open” used in both cases in Luke 24. But what is the recognition about? The answer, I would like to believe, is in the background, far in the distance as indicated by the perspective, which draws our eyes to the weaker backlit shadow of a woman who is preparing food. Who recognizes her for herself, or her work? Rembrandt paints her as an echo of the blinding Jesus shadow, but I think she is the heart of the matter.

What would it mean to recognize her, and not just as a labor factor? I believe it is this: recognition of the transfigured work is a condition for true appropriation of the self, because re-cognition, as subsequent knowledge which meets the first type of cognition (that of the self-giver, of necessity ill-compensated by whatever social system was/is in existence), is the way to open a dynamics in which one may hope to escape self-justifications and limited economic rationales.

One of the two disciples has been so shocked by the recognition that he has jumped up, his chair has fallen to the side, and he has thrown himself at the feet of Jesus, in the obscurity projected by Jesus’ body. There seems to be fear in the eyes of the other fellow who is still sitting at the table.

Capital, labor, and temptation

What is going on from Tunisia and Egypt to Wisconsin and across the world made me re-read the three temptations in Matthew 4.1–11 and Luke 4.1–13:

  1. to change rock(s) into food (read: the miracles of an automated world) vs the multiplication of bread (read: the making and sharing of food, which responds to a broader need than the incorporation of molecules and is an ever-renewed occasion for human relations, giving and receiving).
  2. worshipping of highly visible glory and authority over all the kingdoms of the world (read: global market controlled by a few interconnected companies and military projection capacity) vs serving transcendence (read: source of life, including the mostly invisible, therefore transcendental, self-giving of each other in a truly sharing society, beyond our grudgingly pacifying payments).
  3. I’m stumped for the third one. I said in another post, after Gaston Bachelard, that the movement of the dreamy fall itself not only creates the abyss but reminds one of the verticality of things. Here we are, with the likes of governor Walker willing to walk to the edge of the abyss and taking all of us into division and strife. A kind of present to labor surely, but with a dose of poison. How will all of the social forces avoid suicidal dreams, and remember that there are peaceful ways to stay vertical?

Quoting Luke:

Jesus, full of the Holy Spirit, returned from the Jordan and was led by the Spirit in the wilderness, where for forty days he was tempted by the devil. He ate nothing at all during those days, and when they were over, he was famished. The devil said to him, ‘If you are the Son of God, command this stone to become a loaf of bread.’ Jesus answered him, ‘It is written, “One does not live by bread alone.”

Then the devil led him up and showed him in an instant all the kingdoms of the world. And the devil said to him, ‘To you I will give their glory and all this authority; for it has been given over to me, and I give it to anyone I please. If you, then, will worship me, it will all be yours.’ Jesus answered him, ‘It is written, “Worship the Lord your God, and serve only him.” ’

Then the devil took him to Jerusalem, and placed him on the pinnacle of the temple, saying to him, ‘If you are the Son of God, throw yourself down from here, for it is written, “He will command his angels concerning you, to protect you” and “On their hands they will bear you up, so that you will not dash your foot against a stone”.’ Jesus answered him, ‘It is said, “Do not put the Lord your God to the test”. ’ When the devil had finished every test, he departed from him until an opportune time.

Prodigal or lost son

Introduction

In Jesus’ time, the vast majority of people in Galilee (and Samaria, Judaea, for that matter) lived from an agriculture in which grain, animals, and fruit trees, esp. olive trees and vineyards, were the main elements.

The basic resource, even for the Greco-Roman cities, was agriculture, an activity which required incessant labor, esp. when population pressure (as seems the case since the Iron age, and certainly the Hellenistic period) drove people to cultivate even the steepest hills, spending much work in stone terracing and retaining walls, paths, towers, and the digging of thousands of cisterns in the rock.

What of the distribution of labor? Most of the agricultural work was done by sharecroppers and their families, day or seasonal laborers (perhaps often coming from the same families), tenants on fixed rents, who probably were less common. There were also independent farmers, especially in the hill country, sometimes fairly well-to-do, as in the case of veteran soldiers in the territory of some of the neighboring Greco-Roman cities. Above these people involved in production, and disposing of more authority over the land than them (and therefore more secure access to food and other goods), were large landowners, often priests, esp. aristocratic priests, who were connected to other landowners and even sometimes princely houses through social, cultural, and kinship bonds. And above them all was the king. Herod Antipas was a client-king of the Romans in Galilee in Jesus’ time, whereas Judaea was under direct Roman rule.

The concept of land property was expressed in Aramaic in terms of authority. Many strings were normally attached to this authority over land. The first one was that the “landowner” owed his authority to someone above him with whom he was in a relation of debt and service, and in the end to the divinity. The second one was that this authority depended on a continuous, active protection of those below.

Role of debt

In this ancient economy, given the lack of exact economic measurements (and inadequacy of censuses), there was no way of knowing if the pressures put to bear in the extraction of a “surplus” from the people under one’s authority (at whatever level) were properly set. There could not be a proper accounting or prediction of what could be extracted as taxes and rents, except for specialized crops such as grapes and olives for which yields are more readily calculable. The tax basis was not well known, owing to the climate of the area, and it is likely that people (including many priests) were loathe to see traditional ways changed (for instance, measurements of land were as sown land, not in the form of surveying pure units of area, as the Romans were wont to do. So, the best way to know if the pressure was being properly applied on sharecroppers, tenants, tax-farmers and even client-kings –in a sort of pyramidal scheme– the best way was to set tributes and rents, from top to bottom, in such a way that subjects would be indebted and come begging for relief, which could then be granted (or not).

Remittance of debt was therefore part of the evaluation of the tax or rent basis. It was expressed in a religious language of debts and release which was part of a larger set of values centered on the temple.

So, for instance, one reads about Herod the Great, in the generation immediately before Jesus, remitting part of the annual taxes on three occasions. His behavior appears to be extremely generous, likewise, during the great drought of 25 BC. But his benevolence fits exactly the (ideal) behavior pattern of landowners in antiquity. In an agricultural handbook for large landowners, for example, the 1st c. AD Roman author Columella reasoned that the landowner had to walk a fine line, between being strict in exacting debt payments from tenants—which could make them despair, perhaps even flee—and being generous and encourage a better investment of labor in the land, which he thought more profitable in the long run. From the landowner’s point of view, work, as well as smoothness of the agricultural operations, is what mattered, because it meant better yields. And better yields, in turn, made it impossible for tenants or subjects to ask for reductions in rent or taxes at a later time. Furthermore, piling up revenues of money and goods, enough to last several years, was imperative in ancient times precisely to be helpful—and in turn be acknowledged as benefactor or savior, which therefore reinforced the demands for future reciprocity, i.e. labor—in times of crisis. At the bottom of the social ladder, however, this translated as an impossibility to store and save and was felt as constant fragility and need.

For Jews in Galilee, Judaea and elsewhere, how did the Temple contribute to the system of debt? Because certain kinds of archives and an enormous mass of wealth were kept at the temple and, more generally, because the temple and its sacrificial system provided the sacred guarantee for contracts in economic matters. In the end, this security really rested on something quite simple, namely on the love that the whole people had for the “house of God,” another name for the temple.

What is striking is that the Aramaic vocabulary makes it clear that bonds and debts could also be seen as sins. The same word and root was used for both. People felt constrained to pay as their debts were also sins, i.e. debts to God, in their perception. This system was open to abuse on the part of the authorities in charge of the temple. But the divine guarantee normally put some pressure also on the wealthy not to push their advantage, since the whole of the biblical tradition puts the stress on the idea of a merciful God, who must be imitated. The Romans tried to control the Temple directly, but couldn’t. They had to resort to indirect control by naming kings and high priests and encouraging marriage ties between both

We know that Herod the Great spent fortunes on the Temple and turned it into one of the most magnificent structures in the East. But he was at the same time increasing his control of the land and diverting wealth towards his Roman masters (whether as rents, taxes, or gifts).

The duty of priests, elders and leaders was to prevent, in a variety of ways, the transformation of Jerusalem into a common Greco-Roman city. To prevent this from happening was to afford direct protection to the Jewish producers against Greco-Roman greed. Physically speaking (knowledge of the quantity of harvest, watching over threshing floors), Romans needed the local aristocracy and priesthood, and furthermore needed to tap the religious authority they exercised, since tithes owed were also sins. The priestly aristocracy was torn: go with the Romans and become Roman-like landowners (perhaps with some official capacity), or resist the encroachments and therefore radicalize the position of Jerusalem and the temple.

Kingdom of God

In their resistance to the changes in control of the land, Jews could appeal to the scriptural notion that God was king and sole owner of the land: hence the formulas “kingdom of God” and “kingdom of heavens.” The laws of Leviticus and Deuteronomy are based on this notion, for instance in their development of the Jubilee laws (Lev 25.9-13; Dt 15.2). But under Hellenistic kings, and under Rome, one can see much of the land not only owned by the king and his friends, but also by non-Jews. This had consequences for the application of several traditional laws, for instance the Jubilee law, which in turn became an element of the eschatological language calling for a return to God’s exclusive dominion.

Many people, including John the Baptist, Jesus, the rabbis later, shared this fundamental notion.

Repentance and forgiveness of sins

The debt-system in the society of Jesus’ time locked everyone in their position and made impossible a more extensive debt-forgiveness, because in practice, debt-forgiveness, as part of a forgiveness of sins framed in more general terms could or would not be recognized necessarily by the beneficiary or even others as an act of goodness, but as foolishness, and even rebelliousness.
This is the idea in the parable of the Unforgiving Servant (Mt 18.21-35), in which a king wishes to review his servants or slaves’ accounts. The first one, a minister, i.e. the king’s most important tax-farmer or highest bidder, cannot pay the huge sum he owes him, so the king orders him to be sold, along with his family, and payment to be exacted. But the servant falls on his knees, and implores the king to be patient. The king not only is patient but is so moved by compassion that he forgives the debt. The servant, however, perhaps thinking he has played a good trick on his master, doesn’t hesitate to exact payment on a much smaller debt from a fellow servant , threatening him, showing no pity, and eventually throwing him into jail to enforce payment. The minister/servant is eventually called back by the king who condemns him to jailers or torturers until complete remittance.

Or consider the parable of the dishonest steward in Luke 16 (see my other post). His master is coming and he has lost his position. But he still has his master’s symbols of authority at his disposal for a few hours. So, hurriedly and illegally, he uses them to write off part of the debts of a village of sharecroppers, in the hope that the tenants will reciprocate later in food and shelter. He knows that when his master will arrive, the sharecroppers will thank the master profusely and bless him, making it impossible for the landlord to go back on what has been done in his name. The story implies that God as master may actually accept to be tricked into the forgiveness of sins. It also implies that the highly acclaimed benevolence and debt-forgiveness practiced in hellenized Palestine are unauthorized tricks which do not erase the original dishonesty.

Jesus’ solution to the problem of a debt system in which no one could make the first move appears to be no different, on the surface, from that proposed by John the Baptist and others. His main metaphor was also that of the kingdom of God (50 times in Mt alone and many times also in Lk). He also shared the notion of repentance and forgiveness of sins of those around him.

But Jesus proposed these notions, which were held by all those interested in justice, with a new twist, because when he appears on the scene, according to the synoptic gospels, he forgives sins directly (in several stories of healing physical and mental diseases). How could he dare do this, on what authority? The answer to this question appears most clearly in the story of the lost son.

The lost or prodigal son

The parable of the lost son, or prodigal son, gives an inkling of how Jesus (or the storyteller after Jesus) sees himself in relation to these basic metaphors, the kingdom of God and God as father. This parable, which has been seen by tradition as being at the heart of the gospel, one of 31 parables actually, looks like a version of the story of two brothers, elder and younger: Cain and Abel, Ishmael and Isaac, Esau and Jacob, Jacob’s ten older sons and Joseph, even Moses in relation to Aaron, the seven sons of Jesse and little David… In this kind of story, the second son is often a shepherd. Here too, he becomes a sort of shepherd, but his herd will consist of pigs, animals whose consumption was forbidden to Jews. But the two sons are not the only characters: there are two more actors in this story, the father and the village around, including his own household of house-servants and the workers in the field (sharecroppers?).

The father, who seems to be a wealthy landowner, is a figure of patriarchal authority, over land, wife(s), sons and daughters, servants, sharecroppers. One would expect him to be part of the village or town council of elders, that is to say, deciding in all matters threatening the peace in the village. There is no apparent reason why he should formally divide his estate at this point, since he has sons. Custom would dictate that division be done as follows: 2 shares to the elder son, 1 to the younger one. In any case, the father would retain usufruct.

The request by the younger son for his share of the inheritance is a shocking demand to which the answer normally expected in this patriarchal society is extreme anger, followed by some form of judgment and ostracism or exile, even death in some extreme cases. For instance, Herod the Great accused his own son Antipater of parricide and eventually had him killed right before his own death, because he was too quick to claim the throne (Jewish Antiquities 17.52–53; 61–77; 93–99).

But the father “divides his substance among them” (τὸν βίον, i.e. material possessions indistinguishable from life). There is already compassion, or we the listeners at least can read it into it because we know the end, but do the sons and the village (with its other fathers and sons) and the original audience see it as compassion, rather than weakness, feeble spirit, even irrational, mad behavior?

What is the role of the elder brother at the beginning? Has he remained indifferent? Has he directly encouraged the younger son to ask for the inheritance, or indirectly, by making cohabitation difficult?

The village, perhaps on a hillside or an outcropping over a valley, knows everything or is at least interested in everything, and one may imagine servants and hired workers talking and not necessarily reporting the exact truth. They would be astounded by the father’s lack of severity, and wonder about his authority and the threat to their own.

What happens to the younger son is an inexorable fall, socially speaking. “Not many days later, the younger son gathered all he had…” Did the division of property involve renewed arguments? In any case, it took a while to insist again, do the actual sharing and figure out “all he had”, under the disapproving eyes of everyone. His capital now consisted of sheep, goats, money, equivalent to his share of land. Perhaps he lost in the division, but doesn’t care. After that, he cannot stay in the village or anywhere near, because what he has done strikes at the heart of the patriarchal control of land and the inhabitants of the village may become very threatening to him. He has lost any claim to friendship, as well as any possibility of marriage (?) in the whole area, since news travel fast.

“He went into a far country.” Did the listeners imagine the Transjordanian plateau or the coast, Phoenician / Aramaic / and Greek speaking, but dominated by Greek cities (unless Luke’s gospel refers to the Syrian coast). There, he is a foreigner, a *metoikos*, in self-exile, without a protector or safety net, unable to establish a home, and at risk of falling prey to wrong friends. He has to spend his capital (animals, clothing, money, jewels), without any reciprocity, and at the unfavorable rate proposed to foreigners whose relatives can’t retaliate or reciprocate. So, the ἀσώτως of the text is to be understood as “spending carelessly”, but doesn’t necessarily carries the meaning of moral dissolution.

When famine comes, all his capital vanishes, he has no one from whom to borrow, nothing left to pledge as surety, and he can’t rely on bonds of kinship. The point of patriarchal strategies in land transfer, marriage, and the harsh exploitation of sharecroppers and workers was precisely to accumulate reserves in case of drought and famines (as well as to accumulate power).

He becomes a servant, “glued,” says the Greek, to a citizen of the locality. In order to survive, he has lost his freedom, he is at the call and beckoning of this person. Perhaps there is a hint of forced sexual misconduct also? His master may even have taken some vicious pleasure in sending his Jewish servant to keep a herd of pigs.

His dereliction is not yet complete, however: he is not fed by his master and so attempts to eat what the pigs eat (carob pods?), a temporary solution, not for long, and not filling (as in Lazarus’ story, where the same Greek word is used). No one is ready to give him anything, because charity was normally directed to one’s group, usually narrowly defined. He is alone, and facing possible death.

“He came to himself:” He remembers his father’s willingness, which he doesn’t see yet as compassion. His prepared speech still sounds like a prudently phrased calculation. He plans to ask to be treated as one of his father’s hired servants, meaning that he sees himself as living outside of the village, working in the fields, away from possible taunts and cruelties. He is preparing his repentance, and perhaps ready to take some abuse from other servants?

“He arose and came to his father.” But the father sees him before anyone else: has he been waiting anxiously, always with an eye in the direction in which he left (months ago?). He has compassion, meaning the sort of love a mother has for her baby (ἐσπλαγχνίσθη, 15.20). He runs, like Abraham, the paradigm of hospitality in the Genesis story of the three mysterious visitors, but unlike any dignified adult. And he is repeatedly holding him and kissing him.

In response to this outpouring, the son does not repeat the last part of his little speech (“treat me as one of your hired servants”), but lets his father take over. Is it because he doesn’t dare say it, or does he now suddenly understand the depth of the father’s compassion and the risk that he is taking? The rapidity with which the father acts is critical: Quick, says he, give him back the signs of freedom and authority. There is no resistance on the part of house-slaves, naturally, but the village inhabitants or other relatives have no time to react and question the action, because everyone is swept away into a general reconciliation. The feast, around the fattened calf as center-piece, i.e. something kept in reserve for a wedding perhaps, and which must be consumed immediately, would involve many people, all the relatives and neighbors, preparing, talking, dancing and playing music while waiting for the food to be ready and for everyone to come.

The elder son is busy in the field, doing what sons of landowners are supposed to do in like stories, i.e. watching the hired hands or sharecroppers. When he comes back and asks the young servant (παίς) what is happening, the servant misinterprets (“your father has killed the fatted calf, because he has received him safe and sound.”). Perhaps there is an underlying idea again that the father is weak, and doing very puzzling things?

The son is angry and does a terrible insult, not unlike that in v. 12 above, refusing to go in, and doing so publicly, since the whole scene after the return of the younger son is a public affair. The father responds as before, entreating him repeatedly. The elder son starts hurling terribly insulting accusations: he has been like a slave in his father’s house, and his obedience has never been rewarded. He was never given a young goat to have a festive meal with his friends: another insulting comment, since meals should be inclusive and not the occasion of separation. The rage continues: “This son of yours:” does the phrase imply that the father is like him, or is it questioning whether he is even his?? He adds that the son lost all his capital with harlots (which commentators wrongly read back into verse 13: “loose or dissolute living”). Is that what the elder son wished to do with his friends? With the fatted calf instead of a young goat? The rage might lead to another question: Why don’t you die and let me truly be master?

The father, astonishingly again, shows no anger, which is perhaps misunderstood once more, as in v. 12? In answer to all the constraints of custom and the reference to “obeying commands”, the father says that he didn’t do an irrational thing, but that it was necessary, indeed the only solution.

Conclusion

At the end of the reading, an audience might think: How will the younger son respond to his father’s compassion? with love and devotion, one may imagine. How will he behave towards the “workers in the field”, i.e. the people working and waiting for relief, food, justice? With the same compassion, one imagines again, and the same urgency, risk-taking, and forbearance as those shown by his own father. He will feed the multitudes, heal, and forgive. How will he behave towards his elder brother who is at the door, and in a rage? Here is the greatest risk he can take, because his brother may look at his younger brother as an impostor and hate him rather than trust him.

This tiny beginning in the business of forgiveness, the gospel (after Jesus) sees as potentially expanding to universal dimensions, as a mustard plant growing like a weed to tree-like proportions from a tiny seed, or as leaven acting within a lump of dough.

Further notes on forgiveness and this parable

1. What is forgiveness? the definition of it, or deepening of the notion of divine mercy, entails a redefinition (or rather an infinite broadening) of that of sin.

2. Does forgiveness have a history? One answer to this question is Hannah Arendt’s: Jesus is the inventor of forgiveness (in The human condition) But she seems to think it is an impossible thing, or extremely difficult in practice. Given the impossibility (and unwillingness?) to control the effects of human action, forgiveness, like promise-covenant, are attempts at correction.

3. Another answer to the question: forgiveness is an old notion belonging to the broader one of gift and grace (superabundant grace and gift of life), framed in the Hebrew bible as the main characteristic of the divinity. It was more precisely developed in the vicissitudes of Israelite and Judaean history (yes, but details?). The notion of justice and judgment, as in Job, however, remained overwhelming. See also the apocalyptic texts, still found in the gospels. The notion of debt and forgiveness (release of debt: no more the ancient biblical language of lifting, wiping, removing, transferring, wiping, cleaning) become fundamental in the Hellenistic period and even more under the Roman empire, when it became more clear than ever that all economic actors, no matter their religious pretense or solicitation for cover (paramount example, that of Herod), were in debt and in need of forgiveness or release. On all of this, see Anderson, The history of sin (2009). But note that Anderson doesn’t do an economic analysis, except to suggest that the pervasive metaphor of debt in expressing sin is 1) Aramaic, and 2) perhaps due to the rise of commercial activity within the Aramaic-speaking zone, which cannot be the whole story.

4. The story is throwing light on a most difficult subject, namely the nature of possession or control over land and labor and the seeming aporia that it is given (in fact pure gift, which is formulated as forgiveness). What is at stake? There is a contradiction at the heart of possession. Its hidden nature is of being a gift, and outright possession (that of the older son), or to say it in other words, security in possession (also framed as patriarchal authority in that society) cannot be achieved without recognizing it as gift, and its giver (“donateur”). This can be done only, according to the story, through loss (cf. Aqedah in Genesis 22, the story of the sacrifice of Isaac), and what appears as a more perfect, second giving in which the dimension of the giving appear irrational (climactically so), yet the outcome more rational (“It is fitting”) than the status ante quem, which presented itself as calculation of positions and interests but in fact was hiding bitterness, jealousy, rebellion, and hate.

5. Then, what is sin, what constitutes sin? Is it: not recognizing the nature of the gift and giver? which, given the abundance of the gift (life), means that sin is also of a flexible, potentially infinite nature? The relationship with a unique, personal divinity was the main ground (with power as a way to describe its universality? especially power of creation, which the story in Genesis eventually defined as near absolute: there is a line of development here, from the 6th to the 2d century, with the Maccabees). The logic of economic, religious, and political structures had become more clear and more extensive, its contradictions (especially the religious ones) unavoidable—see already Qumran movement—in the Roman empire. So, the notion of possession and control over resources and labor, including the structure of future control (inheritance), became more clear also, and a fundamental point of debate.

Landowners and tenants in antiquity

The following is background text to Lk 16.1–9. The Roman author Columella (AD 4 to ca. AD 70) has an extensive passage on the ideal calculations landowners should make in land property management, especially regarding the type of labor they should use (direct management with slaves, vs tenants under fixed contracts, vs sharecroppers?):

After all these arrangements have been acquired or contrived, especial care is demanded of the master not only in other matters, but most of all in the matter of the persons in his service; and these are either tenant-farmers or slaves, whether unfettered or in chains. He should be civil in dealing with his tenants, should show himself affable, and should be more exacting in the matter of work than of payments, as this gives less offence yet is, generally speaking, more profitable. For when land is carefully tilled it usually brings a profit, and never a loss, except when it is assailed by unusually severe weather or by robbers; and for that reason the tenant does not venture to ask for reduction of his rent. But the master should not be insistent on his rights in every particular to which he has bound his tenant, such as the exact day for payment, or the matter of demanding firewood and other trifling services in addition, attention to which causes country-folk more trouble than expense; in fact, we should not lay claim to all that the law allows, for the ancients regarded the extreme of the law as the extreme of oppression. On the other hand, we must not neglect our claims altogether; for, as Alfius the usurer is reported to have said, and with entire truth, “Good debts become bad ones if they are not called”. [….]

But when the climate is moderately healthful and the soil moderately good, a man’s personal supervision never fails to yield a larger return from his land than does that of a tenant — never than that of even an overseer, unless the greatest carelessness or greed on the part of the slave stands in the way. There is no doubt that both these offences are either committed or fostered through the fault of the master, inasmuch as he has the authority to prevent such a person from being placed in charge of his affairs, or to see to it that he is removed if so placed.

On far distant estates, however, which it is not easy for the owner to visit, it is better for every kind of land to be under free farmers than under slave overseers, but this is particularly true of grain land. To such land a tenant farmer can do no great harm, as he can to plantations of vines and trees, while slaves do it tremendous damage: they let out oxen for hire, and keep them and other animals poorly fed; they do not plough the ground carefully, and they charge up the sowing of far more seed than they have actually sown; what they have committed to the earth they do not so foster that it will make the proper growth; and when they have brought it to the threshing-floor, every day during the threshing they lessen the amount either by trickery or by carelessness.

For they themselves steal it and do not guard it against the thieving of others, and even when it is stored away they do not enter it honestly in their accounts. The result is that both manager and hands are offenders, and that the land pretty often gets a bad name. Therefore my opinion is that an estate of this sort should be leased if, as I have said, it cannot have the presence of the owner.

Luke 16.1–9

Story of the dishonest steward. This parable is only found in Luke 16.1–9. See the literature. The story assumes an audience familiar with property management and debt system of the time. A proper understanding of the parable, therefore, has to begin with solid knowledge of the economic and legal background.

Some of the questions to be asked are: is the manager a slave? what is the source of his power to enact change in the contracts, granted the willingness of the farmers (tenants)? Second, how is one to explain the fifty percent rebate in the case of olive oil, and twenty percent in the case of grain? Higher class debt in one case, or better calculation? Or irony on the part of the story teller, regarding the real value of olive oil and its marketability? Further, is the absolute quantity about twenty years worth of the stuff? An insurance scheme of sorts then? Finally, what can one say about the level of literacy of the tenants?

Regarding basic economy of the time: first, a system of debt was in existence that drew the maximum labor possible from tenants or rather sharecroppers, and their families (meaning wives and children). Interest wouldn’t be mentioned, but can be assumed to be part of the lump sum that is owed to the master. The steward was authorized to make binding contracts for his master. He was given signs of authority for so doing. Contra certain authors (Fitzmyer more recently, for instance), the steward couldn’t have been pocketing the interest and then expect to see feelings of obligation on the part of the sharecroppers when he returned the unjustly acquired interest. His job is well described in the parable of the Talents: to make money for his master, regardless of the appropriateness of the means, and perhaps make some for himself in the process.

Note on the context: the preceding stories of God’s mercy for sinners imply that one is to share possessions with the needy.

Lost son

There were many things I wanted to tell in class today and simply didn’t get to. Here are my notes on the story of the lost son. Acknowledgment: for many of the ideas below I’m greatly indebted to Kenneth Bailey’s analysis in Poet and peasant; a literary cultural approach to the parables in Luke (Grand Rapids: Eerdmans, 1976), 146–202.

The parable of the lost son, or prodigal son, gives an inkling of how the storyteller (perhaps after Jesus but one doesn’t know this: the parable is only in Luke) sees Jesus in relation to these basic metaphors, the kingdom of God and God as father. This parable, which has been seen by tradition as being at the heart of the gospel, one of 31 parables actually, looks like a version of the story of two brothers, elder and younger: Cain and Abel, Ishmael and Isaac, Esau and Jacob, Jacob’s ten older sons and Joseph, even Moses in relation to Aaron, the seven sons of Jesse and little David… In this kind of story, the second son is often a shepherd. In this story also, he becomes a sort of shepherd, but his herd will consist of pigs, animals whose consumption was forbidden to Jews. The two sons are not the only characters: there are two more actors in this story, the father and the village around, including his own household of house-servants and the workers in the field (sharecroppers?). The village and its sense of values, which include definite views of authority, are key to understanding the parable.

The father, who seems to be a wealthy landowner, is a figure of patriarchal authority, over land, wife (wives), sons and daughters, servants, sharecroppers. One would expect him to be part of the village or town council of elders, that is to say, deciding in all matters threatening the peace in the village. There is no apparent reason why he should formally divide his estate at this point, since he has sons. Custom would dictate that division be done as follows: two shares to the elder son, one to the younger one. In any case, the father would retain usufruct.

The request by the younger son for his share of the inheritance is a shocking demand to which the answer normally expected in this patriarchal society is extreme anger, followed by some form of judgment and ostracism or exile, even death in some extreme cases. For instance, Herod the Great accused his own son Antipater of parricide and eventually had him killed right before his own death, because he was too quick to claim the throne (Josephus, Jewish Antiquities 17.52–53; 61–77; 93–99).

Contrary to normal expectations, the father “divides his substance among them” (τὸν βίον, i.e. material possessions undistinguishable from life). There is already compassion, or we the listeners at least can read it into it because we know the end, but do the sons and the village (with its other fathers, mothers, daughters and sons) and the original audience see it as compassion, rather than weakness, feeble spirit, even irrational, dotty, mad behavior?

What is the role of the elder brother at the beginning? Has he remained indifferent? Has he directly encouraged the younger son to ask for the inheritance, or indirectly, by making cohabitation difficult?

The village, perhaps on a hillside or an outcropping over a valley, knows everything or is at least interested in everything, and one may imagine servants and hired workers talking and not necessarily reporting the exact truth. They would be astounded by the father’s lack of severity, and wonder about his authority and the threat to their own.

What happens to the younger son is an inexorable fall, socially speaking. “Not many days later, the younger son gathered all he had…” Did the division of property involve renewed arguments? In any case, it took a while to insist again, do the actual sharing and figure out “all he had,” under the disapproving eyes of everyone. His capital now consisted of sheep, goats, money, equivalent to his share of land. Perhaps he lost in the division, but doesn’t care. After that, he couldn’t stay in the village or anywhere near, because what he had done struck at the heart of the patriarchal control of land and the inhabitants of the village might become very hostile to him. He had lost any claim to friendship, as well as any possibility of marriage (?) in the whole area, since news travelled fast.

“He went into a far country.” Did the listeners imagine the Transjordanian plateau or the coast, Phoenician / Aramaic / and Greek speaking, but dominated by Greek cities (unless Luke’s gospel refers to the Syrian coast). There, he is a foreigner, in self-exile, without a protector or safety net, unable to establish a home, and at risk of falling prey to wrong friends. He has to spend his capital (animals, clothing, money, jewels), without any reciprocity, and at the unfavorable rate proposed to foreigners whose relatives can’t retaliate or reciprocate. So, the ἀσώτως of the text is to be understood as “spending carelessly”, but doesn’t necessarily carries the meaning of moral dissolution.

When famine comes, all his capital vanishes, he has no one from whom to borrow, nothing left to pledge as surety, and he can’t rely on bonds of kinship. The point of patriarchal strategies in land transfer, marriage, and the harsh exploitation of sharecroppers and workers was precisely to accumulate reserves in case of drought and famines (as well as to accumulate power).

He becomes a servant, “glued”, says the Greek, to a citizen of the locality. In order to survive, he has lost his freedom, he is at the call and beckoning of this person. Perhaps there is a hint of forced sexual misconduct also? His master may even have taken some vicious pleasure in sending his Jewish servant to keep a herd of pigs.

His dereliction is not yet complete, however: he is not fed by his master and so attempts to eat what the pigs eat (carob pods?), a temporary solution, not for long, and not filling (as in Lazarus’ story, where the same Greek word is used). No one is ready to give him anything, because charity was normally directed to one’s group, usually narrowly defined. He is alone, and facing possible death.

“He came to himself”: He remembers his father’s willingness, which he doesn’t see yet as compassion. His prepared speech still sounds like a prudently phrased calculation. He plans to ask to be treated as one of his father’s hired servants, meaning that he sees himself as living outside of the village, working in the fields, away from possible hostility. He is preparing his repentance, and perhaps ready to take some abuse from other servants?

“He arose and came to his father.” But the father sees him before anyone else: has he been waiting anxiously, always with an eye in the direction in which he left (months ago?). This interpretation is guided by the author’s telling of the first two stories in chapter 15: the lost sheep and coin, in which the man and woman intently seek what is missing. In our story, the father has compassion, meaning the sort of love a mother has for her baby (ἐσπλαγχνίσθη, 15.20). He runs, like Abraham, the paradigm of hospitality in the Genesis story of the three mysterious visitors, but unlike any dignified adult, especially father and commanding patriarch, of traditional society. And he is repeatedly holding him and kissing him (imperfect tenses are used).

In response to this outpouring, the son does not repeat the last part of his little speech (“treat me as one of your hired servants”), but lets his father take over. Is it because he doesn’t dare say it, or does he now suddenly understand something he hadn’t seen or even thought about before, namely the depth of the father’s compassion and the risk that he is taking? The rapidity with which the father acts is critical: Quick, says he, give him back the signs of freedom and authority. There is no resistance on the part of house-slaves, naturally, but the village inhabitants or other relatives, that is another matter. You cannot boss them around. The quickness of the patriarch’s decision means that the villagers have no time to react and question the action, because everyone is swept away into a general reconciliation. As the stories of chapter 14 of Luke negatively indicate, they cannot refuse the invitation. The feast, around the fattened calf as center-piece, i.e. something kept in reserve for a wedding perhaps, and which must be consumed immediately, would involve many people, all the relatives and neighbors, preparing, talking, dancing and playing music while waiting for the food to be ready and for everyone to come.

The elder son is busy in the field, doing what sons of landowners are supposed to do in like stories, i.e. watching the hired hands or sharecroppers. When he comes back and asks the young servant (παίς) what is happening, the servant misinterprets or at least souns underwhelmed (“your father has killed the fatted calf, because he has received him safe and sound.”). Perhaps there is an underlying idea again that the father is weak, and doing very puzzling things?

The older son is angry and does a terrible insult, not unlike that in v. 12 above, refusing to go in, and doing so publicly, since the whole scene after the return of the younger son is a public affair. The father responds as before, that is, he surprisingly comes out and entreats him repeatedly. The elder son starts hurling terribly insulting accusations: he has been like a slave in his father’s house, and his obedience has never been rewarded. He was never given a young goat to have a festive meal with his friends: another insulting comment, since meals should be inclusive and not the occasion of separation. The rage continues: “This son of yours:” does the phrase imply that the father is like the younger son, a wasteful individual, or is it questioning whether the son is even his?? He adds that the son lost all his capital with harlots (which commentators wrongly read back into verse 13: “loose or dissolute living”). Is that what the elder son wished to do with his friends? With the fatted calf instead of a young goat? The rage might lead to another question: Why don’t you die and let me truly be master?

The father, astonishingly again, shows no anger, which is perhaps misunderstood once more, as in v. 12? In answer to all the constraints of custom and the reference to “obeying commands,” the father says that he didn’t do an irrational thing, but that it was necessary, indeed the only solution.

At the end of the reading, what might the ancient listener or reader think? Would they think that the younger son is likely to respond to his father’s compassion with total love and devotion? Likely also to behave towards the “workers in the field,” i.e. the people working and waiting for relief, food, justice, with the same compassion and urgency, risk-taking, and forbearance as those shown by his own father? Would he feed the multitudes, heal, and forgive? How will he behave towards his elder brother who is in a rage at the door? Here is the most terrible risk he can take, because his older brother (an Esau figure to the younger son’s Jacob the trickster) may look at his younger brother as an impostor and hate him rather than trust him.

Allegory 1: This tiny beginning in the business of forgiveness, the author of Luke sees as potentially expanding to universal dimensions, as a mustard plant growing like a weed to tree-like proportions from a tiny seed, or as leaven acting within a lump of dough.

Allegory 2: If this kind of stories was told by the historical Jesus, one may be less surprised by the reactions to him of Herod Antipas, his officers, friends and relatives, and the reaction of the temple authorities, who are the elders, closely tied to God’s temple / house, and minding the store. How could they accept the invitation to imitate a non-calculating divinity and let go of their hold?

Allegory 3: the story is about divine forgiveness. But what is forgiveness? the definition of it, or deepening of the notion of divine mercy, entails a redefinition (or rather an infinite broadening) of that of sin. Forgiveness is an old notion belonging to the broader one of gift and grace (superabundant grace and gift of life), framed in the Hebrew bible as the main characteristic of the divinity.

The notion of debt and forgiveness (formulated as a release of debt: no more the older language of lifting, wiping, removing, transferring, wiping, cleaning) became fundamental in the Hellenistic period and even more under the Roman empire, when it became more clear than ever that all economic actors, no matter their religious pretense or sollicitation for cover (paramount example, that of Herod), were in debt and in need of forgiveness or release.

Finally, a further reflection on possession and patriarchal structures of this ancient society. The story is throwing light on a most difficult subject, namely the nature of possession or control over land and labor and the seeming aporia that it is given (in fact pure gift, which is formulated as forgiveness). What was at stake? There is a contradiction at the heart of possession. Its hidden nature is of being a gift, but it appears as outright possession (that of the older son, in his view). To say it in other words: security in possession, or access to *real* estate (also framed as patriarchal authority in that society) cannot be achieved without recognizing it as gift, and its giver (the “donor”). This can be done only, according to the story, through loss (cf. Aqedah in Genesis 22), and what appears as a more perfect, second giving in which the dimension of the giving appears irrational (climactically so), yet the outcome more rational (“It is fitting”) than the status ante quem, which presented itself as calculation of positions and interests but in fact was hiding bitterness, jealousy, rebellion, and hate. (note: I owe much of this insight to Jean-Luc Marion’s *Certitudes négatives*, 2009).

Then, what was sin, what constituted sin? Was it the absence of recognition of the nature of the gift and giver? which, given the abundance of the gift (life), meant sin was also of a flexible, potentially infinite nature? The relationship with a unique, personal divinity was the main ground. Power was the way to describe its universality, especially the power of creation, which the story in Genesis or in Job eventually defined as near absolute. There is a line of development there, from the 6th to the 2d century. The logic of economic, religious, and political structures had become more clear and more extensive in Hellenistic times, its contradictions (especially the religious ones) unavoidable—see already Qumran movement—in the Roman empire. So, the notion of possession and control over resources and labor, including the structure of future control (inheritance), became more clear also. The gospel of Luke is engaging a serious discussion of the politics and economics of its time.

Gift and countergift

Luke 14 tells shocking stories about the recalibration of honor- and shame-based social expectations. Lk 14.12–14:

He said also to the one who had invited him, ‘When you give a luncheon or a dinner, do not invite your friends or your brothers or your relatives or rich neighbours, in case they may invite you in return, and you would be repaid. But when you give a banquet, invite the poor, the crippled, the lame, and the blind. And you will be blessed, because they cannot repay you, for you will be repaid at the resurrection of the righteous.’

This reminder concerning the resurrection is the key to understanding the new system of reciprocity. The parables aim at entirely removing the honor and shame dynamics from its normal province and remapping it on a vertical axis, the person and group to God, with an infinitely remote, ideal, landowner figure, God, inviting everyone. The banqueting at the divine table, the messianic banquet, is indefinitely delayed, yet at hand, in the new companionship of the new brothers, kins, friends, with the story teller at and on the table.

I mentioned the remote landowner figure. In antiquity, divine figures were expressions on a “vertical axis” (temples on mountains, metaphoric or not, large-sized statuary, astral gods and goddesses, powers in heavens) of a social and historical reality which could not be, and was not to be, spoken about directly.

The agonistic gift and expected countergift system, on the other hand, publically defined or redefined the persons and their groups on a “horizontal axis.” That was of utmost concern and permanent interest to everyone. But “horizontal axis” didn’t mean only the visible here and now, the immediately proximate neighbor or kin. Consider the spatial aspect of this “axis.” Note how the great feast, a demonstrative gift—it is not a wedding, which defines a more expansive kind of relation—, reaches out to far-away guests who need to be told in advance of the feast (on this topic, see Green’s commentary, after Bailey), and then told a second time when the time is right for the feast. A key issue, then, was that gifts and eventual countergifts were used to extend and reinforce one’s economic reach beyond family and extended kinship obviously, as well as beyond village or town. This was a critical issue in the politics of the Mediterranean world, tied mostly to the need to increase access to land and labor, and the corollary need to abate risk via property and labor dispersion.

A similar argument can be developed regarding the time dimension. This aspect is not noted by Hénaff, as far as I can see, in his thoughtful, wide-ranging discussion of Weber and Mauss in: “Religious ethics, gift exchange and capitalism,” in Archives of European Sociology 44 [2003]: 293–324). The exchange in the gift and countergift system has a built-in time dimension. Of course, a cardinal principle of the ancient world was to put pressure on those who received gifts (everyone) to return the favors of givers the sooner the better: bis dat qui cito dat, according to Publilius Syrus. But most of the “obligations” so contracted were discharged in time, sometimes a very long time. On the crucial import of this time factor and the need to frame the countergift as something else than a pure return of a favor (a copy of it, that immediacy would indicate), see P. Bourdieu, The logic of practice (Stanford UP: 1983): 105. The grace(s) of the system hid as best as they could the crudity of the calculations. And so, for instance, one needs to ask oneself whether the putative widow and children of a landowner who behaved like the banquet-giver of the Lukan story would eventually receive protections of all kinds—real value— from old “friends” of her husband after his death, or whether the obligations would wear out if not reinforced by the demonstration of power the kind of banquets described in the Lukan story illustrates?

In other words, gifts and countergifts, organized into a benefaction or evergetic system, publically reinforced and re-evaluated the status of people by defining and renegotiating their capacity to draw on and exchange acts of generosity or grace at a distance in time and space. It was a general exchange system, quite as complicated or manyfold as the modern market, with space and time dimensions that everyone was consummately interested in but that no one could master. It has been systematically studied by ancient historians (P. Veyne, etc.).

Although general and reaching beyond the immediately visible borders of kinship and localities, reciprocity systems of antiquity couldn’t take into account all that went into composing the person and the group. The ideal of autarcy—on which see Aristotle et al—was just that, a proud claim that negatively reflected the reality.

There was a more hidden, invisible, real ground for the competitive claims of autarcy by Greco-Roman landowners, and this is what the Lukan story is aiming at. The capacity to project and broaden one’s circle by gracious giving depended on access to land and labor. This access to, and control of, land and labor—“five teams of oxen,” women, slave(s)—depended superficially on the kind of relationships expressed by “giving a great feast.” The network created by honor and shame values was about gaining and securing access to the real means for the banquet, which were the exploitation by military coercion, rents—via sharecropping especially—, taxation, usury, directly enforced labor of women, children, and slaves. That is the massive, hidden source of the wealth advertised as “righteous blessing” and used in a competition for more security, that is to say, the broader circle of friends and obligations.

Do ut des

Or: “I give that you may give”. A new economy is clearly proposed by the author of Luke, but how radical or even anarchic is it? Free gifts, i.e. gifts to people who cannot reciprocate, do not make friends, or do they? Please read Luke 14 for Wednesday, and Green 539-68. We will focus on 14.7-14 (the economy of the gift) and 14.15-24 (the guest list for the great dinner).

Some of the readings on the question of the gift economy are: M. Mauss, The Gift (1924), translated by W. D. Hals (NY/London: Norton, 1990); M. Sahlins, Stone Age Economics (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1972). Annette Weiner, Inalienable Possessions; the Paradox of Keeping while Giving (Berkeley: UC Press, 1992); M. Godelier, The Enigm of the Gift (Chicago: Univ. of Chicago Press, 1999); M. Hénaff, “Religious Ethics, Gift Exchange and Capitalism” Archives européennes de sociologie 44 (2003), 293–324 (especially pages 307–315, for what concerns us).

Temptation (Luke 4)

Commentators propose a number of explanations for the presence of the temptation scene in Luke 4. So François Bovon in his massive volumes, who sets it in the difficult, tense context of the pre-66 AD movements in Roman Palestine. As we know from Josephus, a well-informed and hostile witness, many of those movements were messianic and prophetic. It is difficult to distinguish between the two kinds of leadership. This is obvious when reading the gospels, which show evident unease, many years after the facts, when defining the respective roles of John the Baptist and Jesus. See Richard Horsley in numerous publications. The early followers of Jesus had to confront difficult political issues. We have echoes of them in texts from about 50 AD (Paul in his letter to the Galatians especially, as well as the hypothetical Q, and a proto-Mk?), from circa 80 AD (Mt and Lk), and 100 AD (John, Acts). Among these issues, a most fundamental one was display of fidelity, or faithfulness to a people, its institutions (the temple above all), its history (the Torah), its aspirations (to freedom, usually framed messianically). The early version of the story of the temptation was an answer to suspicions expressed regarding Jesus’ messiahship. The story in Q, with its three elements presumably arranged in the order we still have in Matthew, already dealt with the questions regarding the claims made by Jesus followers. It developed early on because it had become important and urgent to separate the understanding of Jesus’ messiahship from that which existed in Palestinian Jewish society.

One can give plausible explanations for why the Q story was kept by the Matthew and Luke gospels, whereas this tradition wouldn’t be interesting for the Mark community, supposing the author of the gospel of Mark had access to the tradition. One can also explain why the gospel of Luke transformed the story (re-arranging the order of the three temptations) in light of the concerns of a post-70 AD Judeo-Greco-Roman context in which political tensions had become even more exacerbated among the Jewish communities. The disaster of the 66–70 defeat was national, political, and religious. Messianic claims did not simply go underground, disguised in new apocalyptic colors, but they also became suspect. The intensity of the discussions is reflected in a passage among several from Josephus which describes the prophetic and messianic figures who arose in the period leading to the war. This well-connected priest had urgent survivalist’s reasons to please his imperial stoicizing, harmony-loving patrons after the Jewish revolt of 66–70. When he writes his account of the Jewish War, at about the time the gospels of Matthew and Luke were composed, he is quick to assume a take-no-prisoners approach:

Besides these there arose another body of villains, with purer hands but more impious intentions, who no less than the assassins ruined the peace of the city. Deceivers and impostors, under the pretence of divine inspiration fostering revolutionary changes, they persuaded the multitude to act like madmen, and led them out into the desert under the belief that God would there give them tokens of deliverance. [Jewish War 2.258–59]

The most suspect claim, from a Jewish community’s point of view in the post-70 period, one imagines, was that attached to Jesus. So, the defense of a messianic view of Jesus became even more concerned with the radical questioning Jewish communities couldn’t but direct at Jesus followers after the complete failure of all messianic movements.

All of this historical re-mapping, I admit, is fascinating but doesn’t get us one bit nearer the themes of the temptation story. It more or less satisfactorily explains its uses in the proximate context of later authors now called Matthew and Luke, or even its earlier context for its use in Q, but it remains a political, historicist analysis. It is story telling of a less inspired kind.

For a more appropriate literary view, better go to Amos Wilder or Gaston Bachelard, for instance the latter’s L’air et les songes. Essai sur l’imagination du mouvement (1943). Bachelard, in his third chapter on the imagined fall (“La chute imaginaire”), uses Edgar Poe to examine the knowledge of an ontological fall:

This sensibility, sharpened by the decrease of being, is entirely governed by material imagination. It needs a mutation that turns our being into a less earthly, more ethereal, more variable being, less close to drawn shapes.

= Cette sensibilité, affinée par la décroissance de l’être, est entièrement sous la dépendance de l’imagination matérielle. Elle a besoin d’une mutation qui fait de notre être un être moins terrestre, plus aérien, plus déformable, moins proche des formes dessinées. [Page 126]

Beginning with the spirit—like a dove a few verses before—, continuing with the movement in the desert, the in-a-blink lookover of all the kingdoms of the world, and ending at the top of the temple’s pinnacle and the proposed dream of an unending fall, everything flies in this story. The movement of the dreamy fall itself not only creates the abyss but reminds one of the verticality of things. Only saints know temptation and fall and verticality: isn’t that what defines them? As Caird says in his commentary on Luke, the person who goes to the gate of his garden when there is a bit of weather doesn’t know temptation as does the person who is travelling through the gale, and even more the person who climbs mountains. Speech itself in the story of temptation induces breath and the life-sustaining air to move in new ways.

So, for Edgar Poe who knew the state in which, in our dreams, we glide through the air and struggle with the spirit of the fall (ghost?) who wants us to sink, the power of speech is very near a material power, governed by material imagination.

= Aussi, pour Edgar Poe, qui a connu l’état où, dans nos rêves, nous planons dans l’air, où nous luttons contre l’esprit de chute qui veut nous faire sombrer, la puissance des paroles est bien près d’être une puissance matérielle, gouvernée par l’imagination matérielle. [L’air et les songes 126, his emphasis]